330 Wirtschaft
Refine
Year of publication
Document Type
- Working Paper (2228)
- Part of Periodical (978)
- Article (633)
- Book (458)
- Report (153)
- Doctoral Thesis (95)
- Contribution to a Periodical (78)
- Periodical (30)
- Review (24)
- Part of a Book (20)
Language
- English (3033)
- German (1706)
- Multiple languages (10)
- French (3)
- dut (1)
- Portuguese (1)
- Spanish (1)
Is part of the Bibliography
- no (4755)
Keywords
- Deutschland (214)
- Financial Institutions (97)
- Capital Markets Union (68)
- ECB (68)
- Financial Markets (66)
- Geldpolitik (65)
- USA (58)
- Monetary Policy (57)
- Banking Union (56)
- Banking Regulation (55)
Institute
- Wirtschaftswissenschaften (2574)
- Center for Financial Studies (CFS) (1645)
- Sustainable Architecture for Finance in Europe (SAFE) (1428)
- House of Finance (HoF) (813)
- E-Finance Lab e.V. (447)
- Institut für Wirtschaft, Arbeit, und Kultur (IWAK) (360)
- Institute for Monetary and Financial Stability (IMFS) (245)
- Rechtswissenschaft (197)
- Präsidium (111)
- Institut für sozial-ökologische Forschung (ISOE) (91)
Policymakers and researchers worry that the low-carbon transition may be inadvertently delayed by higher global interest rates. To examine whether green investment is especially sensitive to interest rate increases, we consider the effect of unanticipated monetary policy changes on the equity prices of green and brown European firms. We find that brown firms, measured in terms of carbon emission levels or intensities, are more negatively affected than green firms by tighter monetary policy. This heterogeneity is robust to different monetary policy surprises, emission measures, econometric methods, and sample periods, and it is not explained by other firm characteristics. This evidence suggests that higher interest rates may not skew investment away from a sustainable transition.
Our paper analyzes whether a planner should design a taxonomy for sustainable investment products when conventional tools for environmental regulation can also be used to address externalities arising from firm production. We first show that the private market provision of ESG funds marketed to retail investors involves greenwashing, so that a mandatory taxonomy is necessary to generate real effects of sustainable finance. However, the introduction of such a taxonomy can only improve welfare, on top of optimally chosen environmental regulation, if financial frictions constrain socially valuable economic activity. Otherwise, environmental policy alone is sufficient to optimally address externalities.
Corporate green pledges
(2024)
We identify corporate commitments for reductions of greenhouse gas emissions—green pledges—from news articles using a large language model. About 8% of publicly traded U.S. companies have made green pledges, and these companies tend to be larger and browner than those without pledges. Announcements of green pledges significantly and persistently raise stock prices, consistent with reductions in the carbon premium. Firms that make green pledges subsequently reduce their CO2 emissions. Our evidence suggests that green pledges are credible, have material new information for investors, and can reduce perceived transition risk.
Throughout its history, the Fed has operated with a muddled mandate that has not explicitly recognized price stability as the primary goal of monetary policy. The Fed’s success in maintaining price stability and fostering the good economic performance associated with it has depended on how it interpreted its mandate and implemented its policy strategy. In the 1970s and in the recent past, the Fed interpreted its mandate in an overambitious fashion, placing undue emphasis on the elusive goal of maximum employment. On both occasions, the Fed’s strategy proved insufficiently resilient, and high inflation followed. To improve its policy strategy the Fed ought to revert to earlier interpretations of its mandate that acknowledge the primacy of price stability as a policy guide.
The emergence of large transnational enterprises dominating important sections of the tourism industry is a relatively new aspect, determinant and result of the globalization of this industry. The cross-border horizontal and vertical integration, fostered by the creation of a single market within the European Community, takes on a variety of forms ranging from total or partial ownership of firms by acquisition, take-over or mergers to contractual arrangements mainly between travel agencies, tour operators, transportation companies and hotel chains. Based mainly on examples from Germany, this study aims to trace this integration often initiated by tour operators and - to a lesser extent - by airlines. The structural and spatial development patterns and the backward and forward linkages of selected tour operators are analysed. Obviously these enterprises succeeded in building effective marketing organisations based on closely knit spatial networks of travel bureaus either owned and operated by them or connected to them by different contractual arrangements including franchising. Hotel chains and incoming travel agencies in the main tourist destinations are totally or partially owned by the tour operators which became the nuclei of highly integrated corporations. The integration enables these firms to realize a high retention of tourist expenditures and to gain competitive advantages over enterprises only engaged in one branch of the tourism industry. Typical of large German tour operators is that chains of department stores are often the sole or most important shareholders, which in turn are partially owned by major banks. Their stores offer excellent marketing opportunities. German airlines are seldom integrated in tourism corporations dominated by tour operators. On the contrary, in some cases air-carriers interested in decreasing the risk of shortfalls in demand by selling seats to tour operators - try to become direct or indirect shareholders of the giant transnationals. The tourism corporations usually offer standardized services to tourists at reasonable prices. Their market is important and their turnover growing fast. However, the German tourism market is not dominated by oligopolies or even monopolies. On the contrary, based on their flexibility to offer highly specialized tours and services according to the demand of a highly segmented market, small and often tiny tour operators in the German market succeeded in strengthening their position.
The development of tourist centres in the coastal zone of Kenya is connected with the intensive influx of labour from other parts of the country. The majority of hotel employees are provided by this labour. A greater involvement of local labour in tourism has therefore probably not taken place because the coastal population shows only relatively slight inclination towards social mobility as a result of specific socio-economic characteristics (moslems, limited education). However, for the majority of immigrants the tourist economy does not present the immediate pull factor. It is rather the search for general work opportunities that predominantly decides emigration, which is first of all largely directed to the towns of Mombasa and Malindi with their larger labour market. For most people the change from traditional ways of life to the tourist industry took place in social and spatial stages. In this different patterns of step-wise migration have been established for different peoples in Kenya. On the whole labour migrations directed towards the centres of tourism follow to a large degree the currents of migration typical for Kenya generally. Tourism did not in principle connect new emigration regions to its centres. A major problem, however, is the great number of family separations, for the majority of married immigrants live at the place of work without their families. This fact helps to maintain the close bonds between regions of emigration and immigration.